This is the sixth post in a series of posts looking at the question of intellectual property rights in both China and India. We’ve got one more post to go.
Why Intellectual Property Is Insufficient For Economic Development In China And India
The strong focus on intellectual property presented by advisers to China and India miss the ecosystem in which useful innovation takes place. This ecosystem includes, among other things, education, entrepreneurship and openness. For example, intellectual property can only add to growth when coupled with trade liberalization, something India significantly lacks (Gould 1996). However, because a larger market provides a larger incentive for commercial innovation, some researchers have found that with increased market size should come decreased intellectual property (Boldrin 2005). This finding, that for every 2% of economic growth, the duration of IP should be reduced by 0.5% would have significant implications in rapidly growing China and India, but it receives little to no attention amidst the drive for ever stronger intellectual property. Finally, even though intellectual property may stimulate cross-border licensing of technology, it is unlikely to bring a sudden inflow of foreign investment because other facts account for the variation in the behavior of MNCs in different countries (Fink 2005).
Watch out for the Patent Thicket
As China and India are exhorted to increase intellectual property protection and enforcement to higher standards – “harmonization” in the rhetoric of its proponents – they risk emulating the detrimental IP systems of the developed world. The United States, widely viewed as the most innovative nation in the world, has a patent system that has, according to Jaffe, "become sand rather than lubricant in the wheels of American progress” (Jaffe 2004). Even more worrying, the trend in international intellectual property is actually speeding past the American level of protection, raising concerns that the incredibly strong IP in countries will diminish, rather than promote, innovative capabilities.
Patent thickets – "a dense web of overlapping intellectual property rights that a company must hack its way through in order to actually commercialize new technology" – and the "tragedy of the anticommons" – where "too much ownership… wrecks markets, stops innovations and costs lives" – are useful concepts for policy-makers in China and India to keep in mind as they are encouraged to increase their intellectual property. Instead of being incentives for innovation, 47% of firms are using patent portfolios in negotiations and 50% as defensive protection from lawsuits (Boldrin 2008). If China and India grant patents too broadly, they risk overshooting privatization, likely stunting the domestic growth of complex technologies and innovations whose production will be covered by dozens of competing patent claims (Jaffe 2004). This will only be exacerbated by bad standards that do not restrict exclusive rights to truly novel, useful and non-obvious inventions (Boyle 2008).
Are China and India Overshooting Optimal Intellectual Property?
There is already evidence that the two emerging superpowers are making these errors. East Asian countries are patenting at a per capita rate of 4 times the developed world, leading to quick patent quantity convergence (Brahmbhatt 2007). China, whose patent office led the world with 800,000 applications in 2008, is now also home to the most patent lawsuits per year (“Battle of Ideas”). While, prima facie, the enormous absolute populations of China and India will likely make their patenting activity among the highest, given the relatively small sectors engaged in truly innovative work, these figures are worrying. In fact, the same motivations that have been fingered as the causes of the American patent system’s woes – government downsizing and competitiveness – are currently present in China and India, increasing the likelihood that they follow America’s folly (Jaffe 2004).
Another American policy of uncertain quality that is being emulated in China and India is university commercialization. The Bayh-Dole Act, passed by Congress in 1980, encouraged universities to commercialize their innovations through patents, but its effectiveness is highly suspect. Bayh-Dole changed “academic norms regarding open, swift and disinterested scientific exchange” (So 2008). In India, this is already a concern with 71% of surveyed executives feeling “that lack of collaboration between industry and research institutes was the main hurdle to innovation in India” (Dutz 2007). The facilitators of that exchange, Technology Transfer Offices, have “become gatekeepers that in many cases constrain the flow of inventions and frustrate faculty, entrepreneurs, and industry” (So 2008). Yet, China and India are both encouraging university patents (Graff 2007).
Flying Right Past the USA
Unfortunately, simply recreating the flawed American system is unlikely. The world’s largest economic force, the USA, is actively using its trading power to increase international IP standards beyond the current TRIPs-mandated level. Through bilateral free trade agreements (FTAs) and the multilateral Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement, currently being negotiated in secret, the United States is promulgating even more expansive intellectual property policies. The FTAs have strengthened intellectual property rights beyond the high standard already set by TRIPs in dozens of countries. These measures include extending copyright for an additional 20 years, preventing parallel importation of patented pharmaceutical products, limiting compulsory licensing ability, limiting copyright exceptions and limitations through the illegalization of technological circumvention measures, and explicitly extending patents to biological innovations (Fink 2005 PDF). Countries accept these provisions in return for lower tariffs and better quota allotments, but while those are temporary, the expansive intellectual property policies are not.
In addition to all the previously explained reasons why this is likely detrimental to the developing nations who agree, it is useful to note that these policies promoted by the USTR are deeply hypocritical, especially when it comes to copyright. The United States copyright laws give considerable breadth to consumers through the fair use provision. This limitation on exclusive rights has been estimated to contribute $4.5 trillion per year to the US economy (Rogers 2007 PDF). Consumer International, a nonprofit, ranks the United States as among the best copyright policies in regards to consumer protection; notably, it is joined by China and India, condemned by the USTR and copyright industries as too permissive (“IP Watch List” 2009).
Speaking of intellectual property as unidirectional makes little sense when one recognizes that the benefits are neither clear-cut nor absolute. Additional costs of further strengthened IP in China and India will be higher administrative costs, less imitation, and a decrease in the incremental innovation that provides real growth (Reichman 1997).
Other posts in this series:
Re: RE: Are Computers in Africa Really Weapons of Mass Destruction?
Fair enough. In the original version of this I noted that forecasting possible downsides of ICTs is a fine exercise: http://blurringborders.com/2010/03/25/are-computers-in-africa-really-weapons-of-mass-destruction/
We just need to do so in a way that is conscious of the situations on-the-ground, and the two pieces to which I wrote in response do not do so.
Re:
And you need to learn to read a little more closely.
First of all, Masnick isn't the author.
Second of all, being online, even for a few moments a day, is insufficient if you lack the computer skills to harness a botnet.
Finally, if the botnet herder were to be from somewhere besides Africa (a more likely scenario), they'll have trouble using computers in "slums" in their botnet because those computers will be unreliable.
When all you have is a hammer...
When all you have is a hammer...
Psychiatry is messed up on so many levels
See the New Yorker's recent take on it: http://www.newyorker.com/arts/critics/atlarge/2010/03/01/100301crat_atlarge_menand
ID-based Security
The problem with the Israeli focus on 'knowing who you are,' is, obviously, privacy on a more holistic scale than body scanners. Keep in mind that the security measures that have boosted security are not ID-based: reinforced cockpit doors and passengers fighting back.
Re:
Actually, Ronald, for countries at a lower level of innovation capacity, increased intellectual property is a tax levied by the developed world on poorer nations.
Constraing + Abundance
Here's an interesting post about how innovation may occur at the intersection of constraint and abundance: http://www.fastcompany.com/blog/robert-fabricant/design-4-impact/innovation-crossroads
And I like Ethan Z's thoughts on innovation from constraint: http://www.ethanzuckerman.com/blog/2008/11/10/innovation-from-constraint-the-extended-dance-mix/
Berkman
As HLS Dean, Kagan was a big supporter of the Berkman Center. Hopefully her friendships with those people will lead her to do more like this.
Re:
Thanks, Jerry, for catching the error. It's been fixed.
First Sale Case
What was the EFF victory against the contracts limiting the first sale doctrine? That should give some firm footing to any malfeasance by public domain limiters.
Re: Re: Re: What's so special in primary schools?
I wouldn't be so sure, John. See here: http://rconversation.blogs.com/rconversation/2009/02/internet-control-without-firewalls.html
Re: but...
Scott,
I do not think that advertisers go to the search engines solely because they are the gateway; after all, Google'e goal and policy is to move people through their site rapidly. People will be spending more time on the newspaper's site as they read the article.
Advertisers like search engines because, as Battelle pointed out in "The Search", searches demonstrate intent - something very valuable to advertisers.
But that still doesn't mean GOOG and NYT are competitors.
Kevin
Monopoly?
I, too, have big reservations from a public-interest point of view, but as for monopoly... Amazon is making giant strides in providing a competitor for digital books.
Business's Pay
Another reason WSJ can do this is because a lot of companies pay for their people to have access to WSJ. USN&WR doesn't enjoy the same dedicated, rich clientele.
Recording
I had a professor who banned students from recording the audio of his class, but he has been the exception to the rule.
TERRORISTS!
But the terrorists, Mike, they'll use the data to attack us!
Source?
You sure you didn't find that one in The Onion?
Re: Re: Strawman?
Fergie,
Sorry my comment wasn't addressed, but I meant the straw man remark in regards to the Anonymous Coward saying this was a "minor use of power."
On it not being minor, we are in agreement. And on the good-faith effort made at protecting all Internet users, I am in agreement that this specific incidence was done so.
Again, sorry for the confusion. I think we disagree far less than limited commenting will allow us to recognize.
Kevin
Re: Re: The fundamental question...
Most human rights experts would agree that "freedom of expression" includes seeking, receiving and expressing information.
"And of course, the information society's very life blood is freedom. It is freedom that enables citizens everywhere to benefit from knowledge, journalists to do their essential work, and citizens to hold their government accountable. Without openness, without the right to seek, receive and impart information and ideas through any media and regardless of frontiers, the information revolution will stall, and the information society we hope to build will be stillborn." Kofi Annan
(But please don't think I am arguing McColo lost a human right here. Just a side note on comprehensive free speech protection.)
Re: Re: Re: Re: Re:
But when you lose the ability to drive (analogy alert), there is more due process.
But, again, this is only relevant insofar as you see what happened w/ McColo and Atrivo as "minor." At which point we should ask why it should happen at all.